Who is it? | Economist |
Birth Day | August 23, 1924 |
Birth Place | Brooklyn, New York, United States |
Age | 99 YEARS OLD |
Birth Sign | Virgo |
Institution | Massachusetts Institute of Technology |
Field | Macroeconomics |
School or tradition | Neo-Keynesian economics |
Alma mater | Harvard University |
Doctoral advisor | Wassily Leontief |
Doctoral students | Francis M. Bator Alain Enthoven Ronald W. Jones Herbert Mohring Ronald Findlay George Perry Harvey M. Wagner Michael Intriligator Arjun Kumar Sengupta Peter Diamond George Akerlof Eytan Sheshinski (de) Joseph Stiglitz Martin Weitzman Robert J. Gordon Robert Hall William Nordhaus Avinash Dixit Ray Fair Alan Blinder Vittorio Corbo Robert Pindyck Jeremy Siegel Katsuhito Iwai Meir Kohn (cz) Steven Shavell (de) Glenn Loury Halbert White Mario Baldassarri Arnold Kling Charlie Bean |
Influences | Paul Samuelson |
Contributions | Exogenous growth model |
Awards | John Bates Clark Medal (1961) Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1987) National Medal of Science (1999) Presidential Medal of Freedom (2014) |
Robert Solow, a renowned economist in the United States, is estimated to have a net worth of $109.3 million in the year 2024. Solow's extensive contributions to the field of economics have not only earned him widespread recognition but also financial success. As a Nobel laureate and a professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Solow's groundbreaking research on economic growth and development has shaped the way we understand and approach economic policies. With such a significant net worth, Solow's financial accomplishments are a testament to his remarkable career in the field of economics.
Robert Solow was born in Brooklyn, New York, into a Jewish family on August 23, 1924, the oldest of three children. He was well educated in the neighborhood public schools and excelled academically early in life. In September 1940, Solow went to Harvard College with a scholarship at the age of 16. At Harvard, his first studies were in sociology and anthropology as well as elementary economics.
By the end of 1942, Solow left the university and joined the U.S. Army. He served briefly in North Africa and Sicily, and later served in Italy during World War II until he was discharged in August 1945.
He returned to Harvard in 1945, and studied under Wassily Leontief. As his research assistant he produced the first set of capital-coefficients for the input–output model. Then he became interested in statistics and probability Models. From 1949–50, he spent a fellowship year at Columbia University to study statistics more intensively. During that year he was also working on his Ph.D. thesis, an exploratory attempt to model changes in the size distribution of wage income using interacting Markov processes for employment-unemployment and wage rates.
In 1949, just before going off to Columbia he was offered and accepted an Assistant Professorship in the Economics Department at Massachusetts Institute of Technology. At M.I.T. he taught courses in statistics and econometrics. Solow's interest gradually changed to macroeconomics. For almost 40 years, Solow and Paul Samuelson worked together on many landmark theories: von Neumann growth theory (1953), theory of capital (1956), linear programming (1958) and the Phillips curve (1960).
Since Solow's initial work in the 1950s, many more sophisticated Models of economic growth have been proposed, leading to varying conclusions about the causes of economic growth. For Example, rather than assume people save at a given constant rate that Solow did, subsequent work applied a consumer-optimization framework to derive savings behavior endogenously, allowing saving rates to vary at different points in time, depending on income flows, for Example. In the 1980s efforts have focused on the role of technological progress in the economy, leading to the development of endogenous growth theory (or new growth theory). Today, economists use Solow's sources-of-growth accounting to estimate the separate effects on economic growth of technological change, capital, and labor.
Solow's model of economic growth, often known as the Solow-Swan neo-classical growth model as the model was independently discovered by Trevor W. Swan and published in "The Economic Record" in 1956, allows the determinants of economic growth to be separated into increases in inputs (labour and capital) and technical progress. The reason these Models are called "exogenous" growth Models is the saving rate is taken to be exogenously given. Subsequent work derives savings behavior from an inter-temporal utility-maximizing framework. Using his model, Solow (1957) calculated that about four-fifths of the growth in US output per worker was attributable to technical progress.
In the early 1960s the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) was the native land of the “growthmen.” Its leading light, Paul Samuelson, had published a pathbreaking undergraduate textbook, Economics: An Introductory Analysis. In the sixth edition of Economics, Samuelson (1964) added a “new chapter on the theory of growth.” Samuelson drew on the work on growth theory of his younger colleague Robert Solow (1956)—an indication that growthmanship was taking an analytical turn. The MIT economists were thus growthmen in two senses: in seeing growth as an absolutely central policy imperative and in seeing the theory of growth as a focus for economic research. What the MIT growthmen added was a distinctive style of analysis that made it easier to address the dominant policy concerns in tractable formal Models. Solow’s (1956) model was the perfect exemplar of the MIT style. It provided the central framework for the subsequent developments in growth theory and secured MIT as the center of the universe in the golden age of growth theory in the 1960s (Boianovsky and Hoover 199–200).
In 1961 he won the American Economic Association's John Bates Clark Award, given to the best Economist under age forty. In 1979 he served as President of that association. In 1987, he won the Nobel Prize for his analysis of economic growth and in 1999, he received the National Medal of Science. In 2011, he received an honorary degree in Doctor of Science from Tufts University.
Solow also was the first to develop a growth model with different vintages of capital. The idea behind Solow's vintage capital growth model is that new capital is more valuable than old (vintage) capital because new capital is produced through known Technology. Within the confines of Solow's model, this known Technology is assumed to be constantly improving. Consequently, the products of this Technology (the new capital) are expected to be more productive as well as more valuable. The idea lay dormant for some time perhaps because Dale W. Jorgenson (1966) argued that it was observationally equivalent with disembodied technological progress, as advanced earlier in Solow (1957). It was successfully pushed forward in subsequent research by Jeremy Greenwood, Zvi Hercowitz and Per Krusell (1997), who argued that the secular decline in capital goods prices could be used to measure embodied technological progress. They labeled the notion investment-specific technological progress. Solow (2001) approved. Both Paul Romer and Robert Lucas, Jr. subsequently developed alternatives to Solow's neo-classical growth model.